El sitio web “The
Vineyard of the Saker” reproduce hoy una extensa entrevista al economista
estadounidense Michael Hudson (foto de arriba), del cual hemos posteado unas cuantas notas acá
en Astroboy. El tema inicial es la situación económica de Ucrania, aunque rápidamente la conversación deriva a Rusia, China y luego a las estrategias y el rumbo del Imperio. Como siempre, es un gusto leer a gente inteligente, aunque no siempre estemos de acuerdo con sus opiniones. Téngase en cuenta que M. Hudson debe ser, a esta altura, el último economista no neoliberal que queda en América del Norte. El resto ya fue lobotomizado hace tiempo. Acá va la entrevista:
The Saker: We
hear that the Ukraine will have to declare a default, but that it will probably
be a “technical” default as opposed to an official one. Some say that the
decision of the Rada to allow Iatseniuk to chose whom to pay is already such a
“technical default”. Is there such thing as a “technical default” and, if yes,
how would it be different in terms of consequences for the Ukraine for a
“regular” default?
Michael Hudson: A
default is a default. The attempted euphemism of “technical” default came up
with regard to the Greek debt in 2012 at the G8 meetings. Geithner and Obama
lobbied the IMF and ECB shamelessly to bail out Greece, simply so that it could
pay bondholders, because U.S. banks had issued credit default insurance (CDS)
against Greek bonds and were on the hook for a big loss if a default occurred.
The ECB suggested euphemizing default as a “voluntary renegotiation,” asking
banks and other bondholders to agree to write down the debt.
But according to
the international bondholders’ organization – the International Swaps and
Derivatives Association (ISDA) – credit defaults can be triggered if a debt
restructuring is agreed between “a governmental authority and a sufficient
number of holders of such obligation to bind all holders,” making it mandatory.
According to the ISDA’s definitions: “The listed events are: reduction in the
rate of interest or amount of principal payable (which would include a
‘haircut’); deferral of payment of interest or principal (which would include
an extension of maturity of an outstanding obligation); subordination of the
obligation; and change in the currency of payment to a currency that is not
legal tender in a G7 country or a AAA-rated OECD country.”[1]
That sounds
pretty clear. Getting the ISDA to classify the bond swap as a “credit event”
enables holdouts to collect default insurance from their counterparties. There
is little such insurance here, but bondholders can then move to seize
government property abroad. This is what Paul Singer’s vulture fund has done
with Argentina, writing new international law that will apply to Ukraine.
Under London debt
laws (where Russia’s debt is registered), Parliament would have to designate
Ukraine as a HIPC country (such as the African countries Singer has gone after)
to block creditor behavior. I don’t see Parliament doing this for Ukraine, as
its poverty is self-imposed by warfare.
If the IMF were
to claim that Russia’s $3 billion loan is not official, this would rewrite
international law and mean that loans from Sovereign Wealth funds of any nation
(OPEC, Norway, China, etc.) have no international protection. Such a double
standard would fracture the world’s debt markets along New Cold War lines –
with financial warfare replacing military warfare. I doubt that the world is
ready for this “nuclear” financial option.
The Saker: The
Rada has also passed a law allowing the government to seize Russian assets in
the Ukraine. I am not sure if these are Russian state or Russian
private/corporate assets. What would be the economic and legal consequences
from such seizures of assets if the government goes ahead with this plan? Could
Russia take retaliatory measures against the Ukraine or appeal to an
international court?
Michael Hudson:
That would be so radical a step that it is beyond civil law. If Ukraine did
this while still receiving IMF, U.S. and Canadian lending, its creditors could
be held as responsible. Morally that is. The question is, what courts? It’s
true that Israel draws this ethnic exception with Arabs – but does Ukraine want
to use that as its legal justification?
When Cuba or
other Latin American countries sought to buy out U.S. investments at the
declared book value. The result was always attempted military coups. It would
be an act of war. Russia could demand reparations, of course – but from whom?
Could it seize Western assets of countries backing the Kiev junta? Could it
respond by nationalizing German and French holdings, and watch the ensuing outcry
with amusement?
The Saker: The
Ukrainian government has gone out of its way to cut as many economic ties with
Russia as possible. The Donbass has been bombed out and completely alienated,
all defense contracts with Russia have also been canceled, Russian companies
are excluded from bidding on contracts in the Ukraine, Russia has been declared
an “aggressor country”, etc. This means that for the time being the Ukraine
wants to be 100% dependent on the West. Do you believe that the West
(USA+EU+IMF+WB+etc.) has the will and the means to continue to lend money to
the Ukraine or to support the current regime in power? Can the US government
simply print dollars and send them to Poroshenko or are there material limits
on how much the West can do to support the current regime? What will happen to
the Ukraine if the West cannot support it, how bad do you expect the economic
crisis to be?
Michael Hudson:
The “West” is not in the charity business. Its firms do not want to lose money,
and the EU Constitution bans the European Central Bank and European taxpayers
from financing foreign governments. They buy government bonds only from banks –
and few banks hold Ukrainian bonds!
Future Ukrainian
governments could repudiate economic transactions under the junta in the same
way that the Allies cancelled Germany’s internal debts in 1947/48 in the
currency reform – on the logic that most debts were owed to former Nazis. The
present Ukrainian kleptocracy is not a very safe umbrella to sponsor
privatization selloffs and other economic transactions with the West, despite
George Soros’s hopes to acquire its land and infrastructure. Even Ukraine’s
debt to the IMF and other international agencies may be rejected as “odious
debts” that financed a government at war against its own population.
The Saker: It is
generally accepted that the recession of the Russian economy has rather little
to do with the sanctions imposed against her, and that it is mostly the result
of the fall in oil prices. Do you believe that this was a coincidence, or the
the US and the Saudis jointly conspire to drop the price of oil like what was
done in the late 1980s to crash the Soviet Union? Where do you see the price of
oil going in the short to mid term future and do you expect the Ruble to rise again?
Michael Hudson: I
don’t think the fall in oil prices was a conspiracy to hurt the Soviet Union.
Many models have shown the role of financial speculation in driving up oil
prices (and those of other minerals, as speculators turned to commodities to do
what they had been doing with stocks and bonds for years). The Saudis had their
own objectives, in trying to crush foreign competition, including shale oil.
I don’t see the
price of oil rising much, because Europe’s economy is being turned into a dead
zone, and debt deflation is also shrinking U.S. economic growth.
For the ruble to
rise in value, Russia would need to re-industrialize. The neoliberal revolution
after 1991 was indeed intended to dismantle post-Soviet industry, to pull it up
by its roots. H.I.I.D. and A.I.D. operatives bought out Russian companies
playing a key potential military role and dismantled them.
To
re-industrialize, Russia needs to lower its costs of living, headed by housing.
It needs to do what the United States actually did to subsidize its industry
and also its agriculture: heavy public subsidy by picking up “external” costs,
supplying agricultural extension and research services, price supports, etc.
Perhaps Putin can
convince the leading oligarchs to “pull up the ladder.” They may keep their
wealth, but will agree to an economic rent tax to prevent new giveaways and
unearned income from burdening the Russian economy. This will fall heavily on
the companies that foreign investors have bought, ending the drain of dividends.
The Saker: The
most painful sanction against Russia was the denial of credit to Russian
companies. Could the Russians simply begin borrowing from, say, Chinese banks
or are there objective reasons which prevent Russia from doing so? Is Russia dependent
on western banks and, if yes, for how long? Could Russia disengage herself from
the western markets and chose to turn to Asia, Latin America and Africa
instead?
Michael Hudson:
Russia obviously needs to free itself entirely from Western banks. More
important, it doesn’t need their credit. (Look at how China built up its
economy without foreign bank credit!) Russia needs a real central bank to
finance government deficits, and a public bank to extend credit on
concessionary terms. The government can create credit on its computer keyboards
in the same way that commercial banks do on their keyboards. That is how the
Soviet Union functioned for many decades, after all.
There is no need
whatever for Western or Russian banks to finance public budget deficits. There
are plenty of Modern Monetary Theorists (MMT) who can explain how Russia might
do this. It is the only way to minimize the cost of doing business.
If private-sector
(Western, BRICS or even domestic Russian) financial charges are built into the
cost of living (housing) and doing business, it will be difficult for Russia to
be competitive. It needs to do what the U.S., Germany and China have done.
Every successful economy in history has been a mixed economy. Instead, Russia
swung from one extreme to an even worse one – from a statist economy to an
extreme Ayn Rand/Hayek/Chicago School economy in 1991, with disastrous
consequences – as if there were no knowledge of Western financial history or,
for that matter, Volume III of Marx’s Capital and Theories of Surplus Value.
The most effective response would be proactive credit creation to subsidize
reindustrialization and agricultural modernization.
The Saker: How do
you assess the performance of the Russian Central Bank to the combined drop in oil
prices and US+EU sanctions. Many, including myself, were very critical of the
measures taken, yet Russia has fared much better than expected and some are
even predicting a return to growth before the end of the year. Did Elvira
Nabiullina and her colleagues take the right decisions in letting the Ruble
freely float?
Michael Hudson:
Russia let the ruble float because the alternative would have been for foreign
speculators to gang up Soros-style and loot Russia’s central bank reserves in a
financial poker game. Foreign banks would have created enough credit to engage
in naked short selling to manipulate markets and make a killing. Russia is not
adept at this game, partly because Russia’s monetary authorities have been
brainwashed by neoliberal ideology, without realizing its anti-socialist,
anti-labor, pro-bank and pro-rentier sponsorship.
The Saker:
Amongst the various proposals circulated in Russia two have been particularly
strongly supported: the nationalization of “independent” Central Bank and its
subordination to the Russian government and the creation of a fully convertible
Ruble backed by the Russian gold (some suggest backing the Ruble by “energy”,
i,e, oil and gas). What do you think of these proposals?
Michael Hudson:
An “independent” central bank (such as the European Central Bank) means one
that is controlled by private bankers, preventing governments from financing
their own spending and obliging them – and the economy at large – to rely on
private interest-bearing commercial bank credit.
Russia needs a
real central bank serving government objectives – to re-industrialize the
economy, and to rebuild it without the heavy financial overhead that has
inflated housing costs, infrastructure costs, education costs and the cost of
living in the West.
Gold can indeed
be a part of this system – to settle international payments imbalances, not to
back domestic currency. It became clear by the 1960s that no country can
participate in a gold exchange standard and wage war. The gold drain is what
forced the U.S. dollar off gold in 1971 – as a direct result of U.S. military
spending, which was responsible for the entire U.S. balance-of-payments
deficit.
Without gold, the
world’s central banks shifted to U.S. Treasury bills – government IOUs issued
to finance the budget deficit that was largely military in nature. This meant
that global monetary reserves monetized U.S. military spending to surround
these countries and destabilize them if they tried to withdraw from the system.
(That is what my book Super Imperialism is all about.)
The easiest way
to stop U.S. military adventurism is to restore gold and free the world from
having to use a militarized U.S. Treasury-bill standard as their monetary base.
The Saker: If you
had the undivided attention and support of Vladimir Putin, Dmitry Medvedev,
Anton Siluanov and Elvira Nabiullina – what advice would you give them?
Michael Hudson:
They need to see how the neoliberal advice given by HIID and the World Bank
after 1991 crippled their economy’s ability to compete. Privatization raises
the cost of living and doing business. The U.S., Germany and other successfully
industrialized economies rose to world power by heavy public infrastructure
investment to hold down the price of basic needs: health care, education,
pensions, transportation, communications, power, water and so forth.
Their economists
during the 19th and early 20th century explained how government taxes levied on
economic rent – land rent, natural resource rent and monopoly rent (including
financial charges by banks) – would not raise prices, but would be paid out of
economic rent. By contrast, taxing labor and even non-monopoly profits does add
to the cost of living and doing business. Russia was persuaded to untax
itsresource rents and monopoly rents, to leave more for bankers to obtain and,
in due course, for U.S. and European investors to obtain – at the expense of
the Russian tax collector.
If Russian
leaders in 1990 would have read Volumes II and III of Marx’s Capital and his review
of Theories of Surplus Value, they would have seen how much of what critics of
industrial capitalism wanted to get rid of were carry-overs from feudalism.
The missing item
in today’s economic reforms is what classical economics focused on, from the
French Physiocrats through Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill to Marx and his
contemporaries: freeing industrial economies from the rentier carry-overs of
European feudalism. The focus of classical value and price theory was to free
economies from economic rent, defined as unearned income simply resulting from
privilege: absentee land rent, mineral and natural resource rent, monopoly
rent, and financial interest. The aim should be to prevent rent-extracting
activities – defined as purely predatory transfer payments, an economically
unproductive zero-sum activity.
The classical
labor theory of value aimed at isolating those forms of income (land rent,
monopoly rent and interest) that were socially unnecessary, and simply were
legacies of past privilege. The halfway alternative was to tax land rent and
monopoly rent (Henry George, et al.). The socialist alternative was to take
natural rent-producing sectors into the public domain.
Europe did this
with the major public utilities – transportation, communications, the post
office, and also education, public health and pensions. The United States
privatized these sectors, but created regulatory commissions to keep prices in
line with basic cost-value. (To be sure, regulatory capture always was a
problem, especially when it came to railroad charges.)
The Saker: Russia
and China have embarked on what I believe is something unique in history: two
ex empires which have taken the political decision to become mutually dependent
on each other, in fact creating symbiotic relationship. For example, China has
basically decided to become fully dependent on Russia for energy and for
military equipment. Russia, in turn, is hoping that the Chinese economy will
allow Russia to diversify and grow. I would argue that they are in many ways
perfectly complementary to each other. Do you agree with this assessment and
how would you evaluate the potential of the economic/financial collaboration of
these two super-powers? Could Russia and China together, along with the BRICS
and SCO create a new, dollar-free and independent economy and market?
Michaek Hudson:
Two main dynamics are paramount. First of all, in making trade, investment and
monetary arrangements, it’s important to be secure that they will be long-term.
America has provided this long-term security for Russia and China, by making
clear that it is opposing the rising power both of Russia and China (as well as
Iran or any other potential player).
That is the
second dynamic: America’s “divide and conquer” strategy seeks to pick off one
potential rival after another. By joining forces with each other – and by
extending the Shanghai Cooperation Organization to include Iran and other
countries – this obliges the United States to wage a war on at least two fronts
if it moves against either Russia or China. So their long-term relationship is
mutual security against the only likely aggressor.
Capital
investment in pipelines requires a long pay-off period, so it can’t be made
subject to foreign diplomatic interference, as Russian gas sales to Europe are
prone to. Europe seems quite willing to be left out in the cold, by electing
politicians that simply are bought off by U.S. money.
That’s the
unspoken key to U.S. diplomacy: simply bribe politicians, journalists,
publishers and others. As long as the U.S. Treasury can print money without
limit, as long as the world’s central banks are willing to absorb these
dollarized IOUs by buying U.S. Treasury bonds to finance American military
spending to encircle them, America is free of the balance-of-payments and
foreign debt constraint that limits other countries’ military spending.
To counter this,
Russia, China and other countries should develop an alternative monetary and
payments system to the U.S. dollar, a financial system to replace U.S. banks,
and ultimately their own bank clearing through an alternative to SWIFT.
If they succeed
in this, U.S. neoconservatives will have overplayed their hand – and ironically
will have become a force for world peace, by uniting the rest of the world’s
economies, trade, financial and even defensive military systems to protect
themselves from the U.S. threat. If they succeed, this threat will recede – but
the U.S. withdrawal probably will not be a pretty sight, nor will the collapse
of its financial system. The rest of the world will have to protect itself from
the backwash, blaming foreigners.
The Saker: For
all the dire predictions about the future of the dollar, the US continues to
create dollars out of thin air, countries worldwide continue to use the Dollar
for trade, the US debt is still raising, the poor become poorer, the rich
richer and nothing seems to change even though in its foreign policy the US
goes from one failure to another. How long can his continue? Is there an
objective limit after which this system cannot continue? Can you foresee any
event which will force the USA to give up being an Empire and become a
“regular” country like so many other ex-empires in the past?
Michael Hudson:
There is no objective limit to how long Dollar Dependency, Debt Deflation and
Debt Peonage can continue, unless victims fight back successfully. Rome’s
creditor oligarchy gave way to the Dark Ages for nearly a millennium.
Dollar Hegemony
will be phased out as an alternative vehicle to hold international reserves is
developed. That is the aim of the new BRICS bank and monetary clearing system.
What now is needed is a complementary tax system and strategy of public
investment and subsidy.
Rather than an
“event” leading U.S. neocons to give up their aims, the process is likely to
mirror the Western economies’ slow crash.
The Saker: China
and the US a clearly on a political and even military collision course. Yet,
many say that China and the USA are too deeply dependent on each other to ever
have a real conflict. Are the USA and China really in a symbiotic relationship
or can China somehow disengage from the US markets without creating a collapse
for the Chinese economy?
Michael Hudson:
There is no real dependency, because both China and the United States aim at
being economically and militarily independent, so as not to fall into
subservience. The U.S. aim, of course, is to make other countries financially
dependent on it, and also militarily dependent. That is why it needs to keep
stoking warfare – as a kind of protection racket, to extort financial, trade
and investment tribute and deeper dependency in its trading “partners.”
China and America
do have a mutual trade and investment relationship. But it is not “symbiotic,”
because it can be ended at any time without really threatening either party’s
solvency and survival.
China is already
shifting its production away from export markets to the domestic market. And in
terms of monetary policy, it is sponsoring economic complementarity with the
other BRICS members, Iran, South American and African countries.
The Saker: When
you say “China and America do have a mutual trade and investment relationship.
But it is not “symbiotic,” because it can be ended at any time without really
threatening either party’s solvency and survival” could you please explain why
you don’t think that if, say, the US and China had to sever their economic ties
(Walmart & Co.) that would not severely hurt both economies? Is Walmart not
crucial for the low-income sector of the US economy and to keep inflation low
and is the income generated by these “Walmart-ties” not crucial for China?
Michael Hudson:
What China has been supplying to Walmart can now be sold to its thriving
internal market. China doesn’t need more dollars. Indeed, the more dollars it
gets, the only thing it can safely do with them is lend them to the U.S.
Treasury, funding the military’s “Asia Pivot” to encircle China. (That’s how
the U.S. Treasury-bill standard has replaced the gold standard.)
Walmart, on the
other hand, remains dependent on its Chinese suppliers. Its purchasing agents
leave much less profit for the Chinese than they can get in their own market
and in other Asian markets.
The Saker: The
western capitalist model and its formula for globalization are coming under
critique not only from Russia and China, but from many other countries in the
world. Some say that China has developed an alternative model of state
capitalism. In Latin America, “Bolivarian Socialism” is on the rise and in the
Middle-East the Islamic Republic of Iran is also offering a different
socio-economic model. How do you see the future of the capitalist system, with
its globalization, banking and finance model, etc. Do you see a viable
alternative emerging or is the “Washington Consensus” still the only game in
town?
Michael Hudson:
Classical economics was a doctrine of how to industrialize and become more
competitive – and at the same time, more fair – by bringing prices in line with
actual, socially necessary costs of production. The resulting doctrine (with
Marx and Thorstein Veblen being the last great classical economists) was
largely a guide to what to avoid: special privilege, unearned income,
unproductive overhead.
The aim was to
create a circular flow model of national income distinguishing real wealth from
mere overhead. The idea was to strip away what was unnecessary – what Marx
called the “excrescences” of post-feudal society that remained embedded in the
industrial economies of his day. When the great classical economists spoke of a
“free market,” they meant a market free from rentier classes, free from
monopolies and above all free from predatory bank credit.
Of course, we
know now that Marx was too optimistic. He described the destiny of industrial
capitalism as being to liberate economies from the rentiers. But World War I
changed the momentum of Western civilization. The rentiers fought back – the
Austrian School, von Mises and Hayek, fascism and the University of Chicago’s
ideologues redefined “free markets” to mean markets free for rentiers, free
from government taxation of land and natural resources, free from public price
regulation and oversight. The Reform Era was called “the road to serfdom” – and
in its place, the post-classical neoliberals promoted today’s road to debt
peonage.
Today’s Cold War
may be viewed in its intellectual aspects as an attempt to prevent countries
outside of the United States from realizing that (contra Thatcher) there is an
alternative, and acting on it. The struggle is for the economy’s brain and
understanding on the part of governments. Only a strong government has the
power to achieve the reforms at which 19th century reformers failed to achieve.
The alternative
is what happened as Rome collapsed into serfdom and feudalism.
The Saker: What
are, in your opinion, the main consequences of the numerious US foreign policy
failures for the US economy?
Michael Hudson:
U.S. strategists often liken their geopolitical diplomacy to a chessboard. This
may have a geographic sense of space – where is the oil, where are other
mineral resources, which countries are getting strong enough to be independent
– but the resulting diplomacy is nothing like a chess game at all. At least,
not the way the United States plays the game.
But in chess,
both sides move. The idea is to think ahead and anticipate the opponent’s
strategy. Most grand masters study their opponents’ games and are familiar with
their tactics and objectives when they sit down to play.
No such bilateralism
characterizes U.S. policy. Back in the 1940s and ‘50s, the State Department was
emptied out of China experts by Senator Joe McCarthy. The purge was conducted
on the principle that most people who knew much about China, did so because
they were sympathetic with it, and probably with Communism.
The inner
contradiction here was that without understanding China’s policy aims and how
it intended to achieve them, U.S. diplomats were operating in the dark.
Naturally they floundered.
Fast-forward to
today. As U.S. State Department neocon Douglas Feith noted, anyone familiar
with Arab history is viewed as suspect, on the grounds that they must be
sympathetic. So U.S. support for Saudi Arabian oil oligarchs goes hand in hand
with Zionist anti-Arabism. When Feith interviewed an experienced Pentagon
Arabist, Patrick Lang, for a job in Iraq after the invasion, Feith asked: “Is
it really true that you really know the Arabs this well, and that you speak
Arabic this well? Is that really true?” Lang said, yes it was. “That’s too bad”
said Feith. [2] There was no room for someone with an ounce of sympathy for
“those people.” Lang didn’t get the job.
So it’s hardly
surprising that American unilateralism is conducted in a kind of political
vacuum. (“We make our own reality.”) The result is hubris leaving to the
inevitable fall. It’s like conducting foreign policy while wearing a blindfold.
The main failure
of U.S. foreign policy is thus that of classical tragedy: a tragic flaw that
brings about precisely the opposite effect from what is intended. Or as Marx
put it, “internal contradictions” and irony.
The answer to
your question depends on what you mean by “US policy.” What may be a disaster
for the U.S. economy may not be a disaster for the special interests that have
gained control of this policy. U.S. politicians are not so much elected by
voters as bid for by their campaign contributors. The financial weight of Wall
Street and, behind it, the oil industry as well as the real estate sector and
the military-industrial complex has benefited the 1%? It’s been a success for
them – at least in the sense of U.S. policy reflecting what the 1% want. It’s
been a failure for the 99%, of course. And these days, the 1% may be so
short-sighted that their aims may bring about the opposite of what they intend.
This would include America’s Near Eastern failure to understand the dynamics of
Islamic societies.
If by “failures”
you mean the damage that has been done, I would rank the most serious one to be
America’s opposition to secular governments in the Islamic lands, leading to
the most extremist, literalist readings of Islam, capped by Saudi Wahabism.
The fatal turn
began in 1953 with the U.S. overthrow of Iran’s Mossedegh government. The
intention was simply to protect British and American oil, not to back Islamic
extremism. But supporting the Shah in a Latin American-style dictatorship left
only one practical venue for opposition: the Islamic mosques and other
religions centers. Khomeini led the fight for freedom against the Shah’s
dictatorship, torture chambers and subservience to U.S. foreign policy.
In Afghanistan,
of course, the U.S. created Al Qaeda and backed Bin Laden to fight against the
secular regime backed by Soviet Russia. The subsequent history of U.S. involvement
in Iraq, Syria, Lebanon and elsewhere in the Near East has been one of
supporting Saudi Wahabism. And it’s been a disaster from any point of view.
Anthropologists
have decried the blind spot of American policy to the ethnic and religious
divisions at work – not only the obvious antagonism between Shi’ite and Sunni
Moslems, but between the pastoral nomadism that was the context for Wahabi
extremism and anti-feminist doctrine. The Near East has been dominated by
sheikdoms for the past four thousand years. But U.S. policy lumps all Islam
together, missing these divisions.
Being a
democracy, America can no longer afford a land war. No democratic country can.
So the only military option that is practically available is to bomb and
destroy. That has been U.S. policy from the Near East to the former Soviet
sphere, from Latin America to Africa in supporting dictators that will follow
U.S. foreign policy and that of its mining companies, oil companies and other
multinationals.
U.S. foreign
policy is simply “Do what we say, privatize and sell to U.S. buyers, and permit
them to avoid paying taxes by transfer pricing and financialization gimmicks,
or we will destroy you like we did Libya, Iraq, Syria et al.”
The result is to
unify foreign countries into a resistance, obliging them to create an
alternative path to U.S. financial hegemony. If America had pursued a policy of
mutual benefit, other countries probably would have let America make money from
them, as part of a mutual gain. But the U.S. stance is to grab everything, not
share. This selfishness is what is most self-defeating ultimately.
Notas:
Katy Burne,
“ISDA: Greek Debt Restructuring Triggers CDS Payouts,” Wall Street Journal,
March 9, 2012.
Steve Clemons,
“Pat Lang & Lawrence Wilkerson Share Nightmare Encounters with Feith,
Wolfowitz, and Tenet,” http://washingtonnote.com/pat_lang_lawren/ , citing Jeff
Stein, Congressional Quarterly.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario